30217911911 Encyclopædia Britannica, Volume 13 — HousingArthur Shadwell

HOUSING. The housing of the poorer classes has becomea pressing problem in all populous Western countries, and hasengaged, in a varying but constantly increasing measure, theattention of legislative and administrative bodies and of philanthropicindividuals and societies. The general interest was signalized by an International Congress held in London in 1907.The recognition of the problem is due in the first instance to thescience of public health, the rise of which dates from the secondquarter of the 19th century; and in the second instance to thegrowth of urban populations consequent on the developmentof manufacturing industries and of trading and transportingagencies, both of which tend to mass increasing numbers of peoplein convenient centres. To have a clear view of the subject itis necessary to distinguish these factors and their respectiveinfluence upon the problem. Urban congestion is quite secondary,and only important because and so far as it has a prejudicialeffect upon health and strength. Further, the requirements onthe scientific side, made on behalf of public health, are of verymuch wider application and more expansive than those whicharise from the mere growth of urban population. That is obviousat once from the fact that they extend to rural housing, whichhas indeed become a prominent feature of the question inrecent years. To ascribe the housing problem to the “factorysystem,” as some writers have done, is to put forward an inadequateand misleading view of it. It is, in fact, particularlyacute in some places totally devoid of factories and least acutein some purely factory towns. If the factory system wereabolished with all its effects the housing question would remain.But there is a more important distinction than extent of application.The requirements of public health are indeterminate andinterminable; knowledge increases, or rather changes, and thestandard constantly rises. It is the changing standard whichgives most trouble; housing at one period thought good enoughis presently condemned. Fifty years ago no house existedwhich would satisfy modern sanitary standards, and the mansionsof the great were in some respects inferior to the worst quartersto-day. And to this process there is no end. It is quite conceivablethat urban congestion might cease to be a difficulty atall. That actually happens in particular towns where thepopulation is stationary or diminishing. One whole nation(France) has already reached that point, and others are movingtowards it at varying rates. But even where the supply ofhouses exceeds the demand and many stand empty, the housingproblem remains; condemnation of existing accommodationcontinues and the effort to provide superior houses goes on. Inother words, there are two main aspects of the housing question,quality and quantity; they touch at various points and interact,but they are essentially distinct. The problem of quantity maybe “solved,” that of quality has no finality.

The importance attached to housing is much enhanced bythe general tendency to lay stress on the material conditionsof life, which characterizes the present age. Among materialconditions environment takes a leading place, largely under theinfluence of the theory of evolution in a popular and probablyerroneous form; and among the factors of environment thehome assumes a more and more prominent position. There isreason in this, for whatever other provision be made for workor recreation the home is after all the place where people spendmost of their time. Life begins there and generally ends there.At the beginning of life the whole time is spent there and homeconditions are of paramount importance to the young, whosephysical welfare has become the object of increasing care. Butthe usual tendency to run to extremes has asserted itself. Itmay be admitted that it is extremely difficult to raise thecharacter and condition of those who live in thoroughly badhome surroundings, and that an indispensable or preliminarystep is to improve the dwelling. But if in pursuit of this objectother considerations are lost sight of, the result is failure. Badhousing is intimately connected with poverty; it is, indeed,largely a question of poverty now that the difference betweengood and bad housing is understood and the effects of the latterare recognized. The poorest people live under the worst housingconditions because they are the cheapest; the economic factorgoverns the situation. Poverty again is associated with badhabits, with dirt, waste, idleness and vice, both as cause andas effect. These factors cannot be separated in real life; theyact and react upon each other in such a way that it is impossibleto disentangle their respective shares in producing physicaland moral evils. To lay all responsibility upon the structuralenvironment is an error constantly exposed by experience.

Defective quality embraces some or all of the followingconditions—darkness, bad air, damp, dirt and dilapidation.Particular insanitary conditions independent of the structureare often associated; namely defects of water-supply, drainage,excrement and house refuse removal, back-yards and surroundingground; they contribute to dirt, damp and bad air. Defectivequantity produces high rents and overcrowding, both ofwhich have a prejudicial effect upon health; the one by diminishingexpenditure on other necessaries, the other by fouling theatmosphere and promoting the spread of infectious illness.The physical effects of these conditions have been demonstratedby comparative statistics of mortality general andspecial; among the latter particular stress is laid on the mortalityof infants, that from consumption and from “zymotic” diseases.The statistical evidence has been especially directed to theeffects of overcrowding, which can be stated with greater precisionthan other insanitary conditions. It generally takes theform of comparing the death-rates of different areas having widelycontrasted densities of population or proportions of personsto a given space. It is not necessary to quote any of thesefigures, which have been produced in great abundance. Theybroadly establish a connexion between density and mortality;but the inference that the connexion can be reduced to a precisenumerical statement and that the difference of mortality shownis all due to overcrowding or other housing conditions is highlyfallacious. Many other factors ought to be taken into account,such as the age-distribution of the population, the birth-rate,the occupations, means, character and habits of the people,the geographical situation, the number of public institutions,hospitals, workhouses, asylums and so forth. The fallacioususe of vital statistics for the purpose of proving some particularpoint has become so common that it is necessary to enter awarning against them; the subject of housing is a popularfield for the exercise of that art, though there is no need of it.

The actual state of housing in different countries and localities,the efforts made to deal with it by various agencies, the subsidiarypoints which arise in connexion with it and the resultsattained—all these heads embrace such a vast mass of factsthat any attempt to treat them fully in detail would run toinordinate length. It must suffice to review the more salientpoints; and the most convenient way of doing so is to dealfirst with Great Britain, which has led the way historicallyin extent of need, in its recognition and in efforts to meet it,adding some notes upon other countries, in which the questionis of more recent date and for which less information is available.

The United Kingdom

The importance of housing and the need of improvementhad by 1909 received public recognition in England for nearly70 years, a period coinciding almost exactly with the systematicstudy of sanitation or public health. The active movementdefinitely began about 1841 with voluntary effort in whichLord Shaftesbury was the most prominent and active figure.The motive was philanthropic and the object was to improvethe condition of the working classes. It took the form ofsocieties; one was the “Metropolitan Association for Improvingthe Dwellings of the Industrial Classes,” incorporated in 1845but founded in 1841; another was the “Society for Improvingthe Condition of the Labouring Classes,” originally the“Labourers’ Friend Society,” of which the Prince Consortbecame president. That fact and the statement of the Societyconcerning improved housing that “the moral were almostequal to the physical benefits,” sufficiently prove that publicinterest in the subject and a grasp of its significance alreadyexisted at that date. Legislation followed not long after andhas continued at intervals ever since.

Legislation.—Twenty-eight Housing and Health Acts, passedbetween 1851 and 1903, are enumerated by Mr Dewsnup, whosemonograph on The Housing Problem in England is the fullest account of the subject published. The first was the Shaftesbury Act of 1851for the establishment of lodging-houses for the working classes;the last was the Housing of the Working Classes Act of 1903. TheShaftesbury Act had in view the provision by local authorities ofgood lodging-houses for the better class of artisans, and particularlyof single persons, male and female, though families were also contemplated.It was accompanied in the same year by another act,not included in the list of twenty-eight, for the regulation and controlof common lodging-houses, from which Mr Dewsnup reasonablyinfers that the object of Lord Shaftesbury, who inspired both acts,was the separation of the casual and disorderly class frequentingcommon lodging-houses from the more regularly employed andrespectable workers who were sometimes driven to use them forlack of other accommodation. At any rate this early legislationembodied the principle of differential treatment and showed a graspof the problem not always visible in later procedure. The mostimportant of the subsequent acts were those of 1855 and 1866, bothintended to encourage private enterprise in the provision of working-classdwellings; the Torrens Act of 1868 (Artisans’ and Labourers’Dwellings Act) for the improvement or demolition of existingbuildings; the Cross Act of 1875 (Artisans’ and Labourers’ DwellingsImprovement Act), for extending that process to larger areas; thePublic Health Act of 1875; the Housing of the Working Classes Actof 1885 following the report of the Royal Commission on the Housingof the Working Classes, of which King Edward, then prince ofWales, was a member; the Housing of the Working Classes Act of1890; the Public Health (London) Act of 1891. The acts of 1875(Public Health), of 1890 and of 1891 are still in force. The story ofthis half-century of legislation (which also includes a number ofScotch and Irish acts, local private acts and others bearing on thequestion) is one of tentative efforts first in one direction then inanother, of laws passed, amended, extended, consolidated, superseded.Many of the enactments, originally of limited application,were subsequently extended, and the principal laws now in forceapply to the whole of the United Kingdom. Two main objects canbe distinguished—(1) the treatment of existing dwellings by demolitionor improvement; (2) the construction of new ones. Thesecond head is further subdivided into (a) municipal action, (b)private action. These objects have been alternately promoted bylegislative measures conceived and carried out on no systematicplan, but gradually and continuously developed into an effectivebody of law, particularly with regard to the means of dealing withexisting insanitary dwellings. The advancing requirements ofpublic health are clearly traceable in the series of enactments directedto that end. The Nuisances Removal Act of 1855 took cognizanceof premises in such a state as to be “a nuisance or injurious tohealth,” and made provision for obtaining an order to prohibit theuse of such premises for human habitation. In the same act overcrowdingobtained statutory recognition as a condition dangerous orprejudicial to health, and provision was made for compelling itsabatement. The campaign against bad housing conditions thusinaugurated by the legislature was extended by subsequent acts in1860, 1866 and 1868, culminating in the Cross Act of 1875 for thedemolition (and reconstruction) of large insanitary areas and theextremely important Public Health Act of the same year. Theconstructive policy, begun still earlier in 1851 by Lord Shaftesbury’sAct, was concurrently pursued, and for some years more activelythan the destructive; but after 1866 the latter became more prominent,and though the other was not lost sight of it fell into thebackground until revived by the Royal Commission of 1885 and thehousing legislation which followed, particularly the Housing of theWorking Classes Act of 1890, amending and consolidating previousacts.

The laws in operation at the beginning of 1909 were thePublic Health Acts of 1875 and 1891 (London), as amended bysubsequent minor measures, and the Housing of the WorkingClasses Act of 1890, amended in 1894, 1900 and 1903. ThePublic Health Acts place upon the local sanitary authoritythe obligation of securing, under by-laws, the proper construction,draining and cleaning of streets, removal of house refuse andbuilding of houses, including structural details for the preventionof damp and decay, the provision of sanitary conveniences andan adequate water-supply; also of inquiring into and removingnuisances, which include any premises in such a condition asto be a nuisance or injurious to health and any house so overcrowdedas to be dangerous or injurious to health. For thepurpose of carrying out these duties the local authority has thepower of inspection, of declaring a building unfit for humanhabitation and of closing it by order. The Housing Acts givemore extended power to the local authority to demolish insanitarydwellings and clear whole areas or “slums,” and alsoto construct dwellings for the working classes with or withoutsuch clearance; they also retain the older provisions for encouragingprivate enterprise in the erection of superior dwellings forthe working classes. The procedure for dealing with insanitaryproperty under these Acts is too intricate to be stated in detail;but, briefly, there are two ways of proceeding. In the firstthe local authority, on receiving formal complaint of an unhealthyarea, cause an inspection to be made by their medical officer,and if the report in their opinion justifies action, they mayprepare an “improvement scheme,” which is submitted to theLocal Government Board. The Board holds an inquiry, and, ifsatisfied, issues a provisional order, which has to be confirmedby a special act of parliament, under which the local authoritycan proceed to demolish the houses concerned after payingcompensation to the owners. This procedure, which is authorizedby part i. of the act of 1890, is obviously both cumbrous andcostly. The second way, provided for by part ii. of the act,is much simpler and less ambitious; it only applies to singlehouses or groups of houses. The medical officer in the courseof his duty reports to the local authority any houses which arein his opinion unfit for human habitation; the local authoritycan then make an order to serve notices on the owners to repairthe houses at their own expense. Failing compliance on thepart of the owners, an order for closing the houses can be obtained;and if nothing is done at the end of three months an order fordemolition can be made. Buildings injurious by reason of theirobstructive character (e.g. houses built back to back so as tobe without through ventilation and commonly called “back-to-back”houses) can be dealt with in a similar manner. Smallareas containing groups of objectionable houses of either kindmay be made the subject of an improvement scheme, as above.Where areas are dealt with under improvement schemes thereis a certain obligation to re-house the persons displaced. Buildingschemes are provided for under part iii. of the act. Land maybe compulsorily purchased for the purpose and the moneyrequired may be raised by loans under certain conditions. Theprovisions thus summarized were considerably modified by the“Housing, Town Planning, &c., Act,” passed at the end of 1909.It rendered obligatory the adoption (previously permissive)of the housing provisions (part iii.) of the act of 1890 by localauthorities, simplified the procedure for the compulsory purchaseof land required for the purpose and extended the facilities forobtaining loans. It further gave power to the Local GovernmentBoard to compel local authorities to put in force the act of 1890in regard both to existing insanitary housing and the provisionof new housing. Power was also given to county councils toact in default of rural district councils in regard to new housing.The procedure for dealing with insanitary houses by closingand demolition under part ii. (see above) was rendered morestringent. The general intention of the new act was partlyto facilitate the administration of the previous one by localauthorities and partly to provide means of compelling supineauthorities to take action. Its town-planning provisions arenoted below.

Effects of Legislation.—The efficacy of laws depends very largelyon their administration; and when they are permissive anddependent on the energy and discretion of local bodies theiradministration varies greatly in different localities. That hasbeen the case with the British housing and health laws, and isone cause of dissatisfaction with them. But in the aggregatethey have effected very great improvement. Public action haschiefly taken effect in sanitary reform, which includes theremoval of the worst housing, through demolition or alteration,and general sanitary improvements of various kinds. In somelarge towns the worst parts have been transformed, masses ofold, narrow, crowded, dilapidated and filthy streets and courtshave been swept away at one blow or by degrees; other partshave been reconstructed or improved. The extent to whichthis has been accomplished is not generally recognized. Itis not easily demonstrated, and to realize it local knowledge,observation and memory are needed. The details of the storyare hidden away in local annals and official reports; and writerson the subject are usually more concerned with what has notthan with what has been done. Both the Public Health and theHousing Acts have had a share in the improvement effected. The operation of the former is slow and gradual, but it is continuousand far more general than that of the latter. It embracesmany details which are not usually taken into account in discussinghousing, but which have as much bearing on the healthinessof the home as the structure itself. The Public Health Actshave further had a certain preventive influence in laying downa standard for the erection of new houses by the ordinarycommercial agencies. Such houses are not ideal, because thecommercial builder studies economy and the question of rent;but the standard has risen, and building plans involving insufficientlight and air, such as once were general, have nowfor several years been forbidden almost everywhere. Supervisionof commercial building is, in fact, vastly more importantthan the erection of dwellings by public or philanthropic agencies,because it affects a vastly larger proportion of the population.The influence of the Public Health Acts in improving the conditionsof home life cannot be estimated or summarized, but itis reflected in the general death-rate, which fell steadily in theUnited Kingdom from 21.1 per 1000 in 1878 to 15.4 per 1000in 1907.

Insanitary Areas.—The operation of the Housing Acts ismore susceptible of being stated in figures, though no fully comprehensiveinformation is available. The original Shaftesbury Actof 1851 for erecting municipal lodging-houses appears to have beenpractically inoperative and little or nothing was done for a goodmany years. In 1864, however, Liverpool obtained a private actand entered on the policy of improvement by the demolition ofinsanitary dwellings on a considerable scale, following it up in 1869by re-housing. In 1866 Glasgow, also under a private act, createdan Improvement Trust, administered by the city council, and embarkedon a large scheme of improvement. These seem to havebeen the earliest examples. The Torrens Act of 1868, which embodiedthe improvement policy, did not produce much effect. Accordingto a parliamentary return, during the years 1883–1888, proceedingswere only taken under this act in respect of about 2000 houses inLondon and four provincial towns. More advantage was taken ofthe Cross Act of 1875, which was intended to promote large improvementschemes. Between 1875 and 1885 23 schemes involvinga total area of 51 acres and a population of about 30,000 wereundertaken, in London; and 11 schemes in provincial towns. Byfar the most important of these, and the largest single scheme everundertaken, was one carried out in Birmingham. It affected anarea of 93 acres and involved a net cost of £550,000. Altogetherbetween £4,000,000 and £5,000,000 were raised for improvementschemes under those acts. After the Housing Act of 1890 theclearance policy was continued in London and extended in theprovinces. During the period 1891–1905 loans to the amount ofabout £2,300,000 were raised for improvement schemes by 28provincial towns in England and Wales. The largest of these wereLeeds (£923,000), Manchester (£285,000), Liverpool (£178,000),Sheffield (£131,000), Brighton (£112,000). The Leeds schemeaffected an area of 75 acres, which was cleared at a cost of £500,000.In London the area cleared was raised to a total of 104 acres; thegross cost, down to March 31, 1908, was £3,417,337, the net cost£2,434,096, and the number of persons displaced 48,525. Glasgowhas under its Improvement Trust cleared an area of 88 acres witha population of 51,000. At the same time the policy of dealingwith houses unfit for habitation singly or in small groups by compellingowners to improve them has been pursued by a certainnumber of local authorities. In the six years 1899–1904 actionwas taken each year on the average in respect of about 5000 housesby some 400 local authorities large and small outside London.Representations were made against 33,746 houses, 17,210 wererendered fit for habitation, closing orders were obtained against4220 and demolition orders against 748. These figures do not includecases in which action was taken under local acts and PublicHealth Acts. In Manchester, between 1885 and 1905, nearly 10,000“back-to-back” houses were closed and about half of them reopenedafter reconstruction. Hull, an old seaport town with agreat deal of extremely bad housing, has made very effective use ofthe method of gradual improvement and has transformed its worstareas without appearing in any list of improvement schemes. Inrecent years this procedure has been systematically taken up inBirmingham and other places, and has been strongly advocated byMr J. S. Nettlefold (Practical Housing) in preference to large improvementschemes on account of the excessive expense involvedby the latter in buying up insanitary areas. In the six years 1902–1907Birmingham dealt with 4111 houses represented as unfit forhabitation; 1780 were thoroughly repaired, 1005 were demolished;the rest were under notice or in course of repair at the end of theperiod. Among other towns which have adopted this policy areLiverpool, Cardiff, York, Warrington and two London boroughs.

Building.—On the constructive side the operation of the HousingActs has been less extensive and much less general. In Londonalone has the erection of working-class dwellings by municipalaction and organized private enterprise assumed large proportions.Philanthropic societies were first in the field and date from a periodanterior to legislation, which however, stimulated their activity formany years by affording facilities. Fourteen organizations were inoperation in London prior to 1890 and some of them on a large scale;others have since been formed. The earliest was the MetropolitanAssociation for Improving the Dwellings of the Industrial Classes,whose operations date from 1847; it has built 1441 tenementscontaining 5105 rooms. The largest of these enterprises are theImproved Industrial Dwellings Company (1864), which has built5421 tenements containing 19,945 rooms; the Peabody Fund(1864) with 5469 tenements containing 12,328 rooms; the Artisans’,Labourers’ and General Dwellings Company (1867), with 1467tenements containing 3495 rooms, and 6195 cottage dwellings;the East-End Dwellings Company (1885) with 2096 tenementscontaining 4276 rooms; the Guinness Trust (1889) with 2574tenements containing 5338 rooms. The Artisans’ Dwellings Companyalone has housed upwards of 50,000 persons. In addition tothese there are the Rowton Houses (1892), which are hotels forworking men, six in number, accommodating 5162 persons. Sofar as can be estimated, private enterprise has housed some 150,000persons in improved dwellings in London on a commercial basis.The early activity of the building companies was largely due to thepolicy of the Metropolitan Board of Works, which adopted extensiveimprovement schemes and sold the cleared sites to the companies,who carried out the re-housing obligations imposed by the law.Since the London County Council, which replaced the Board ofWorks in 1889, adopted the policy of undertaking its own re-housing,their activity has greatly diminished. The buildings erected by themare nearly all in the form of blocks of tenements; the Artisans’Dwellings Company, which has built small houses and shops inoutlying parts of London, is an exception. The tenement blocks arescattered about London in many quarters. For instance the PeabodyFund has 18 sets of dwellings in different situations, theMetropolitan Association has 14; the Artisans’ Dwellings Companyhas 10; the Guinness Trust has 8. In 1909 an important additionto the list of philanthropic enterprises in London was put in handunder the will of Mr W. R. Sutton, who left nearly £2,000,000 forthe purpose of providing improved working-class dwellings. Theerection of tenement blocks containing accommodation for 300families was begun on a site in the City Road. In only a few provincialtowns has private enterprise contributed to improved housingin a similar manner and that not upon a large scale; among them areNewcastle, Leeds, Hull, Salford and Dublin.

Municipal Building has been more generally adopted. Thefollowing details are taken from Mr W. Thompson’s Housing up toDate, which gives comprehensive information down to the end of1906. The number of local authorities which had then availedthemselves of part iii. of the Housing Act of 1890, which providesfor the erection of working-class dwellings, was 142. They werethe London County Council, 12 Metropolitan Boroughs, 69 CountyBoroughs and Town Councils, 49 Urban District Councils and 12Rural District Councils. The dwellings erected are classified aslodging-houses, block dwellings, tenement houses, cottage flats andcottages. Lodging-houses have been built by 12 towns, of which8 are in England, 3 in Scotland (Glasgow, Aberdeen and Leith) and1 in Ireland (Belfast). The total number of beds provided was6218, of which Glasgow accounts for 2414, London for 1846, Manchesterand Salford together for 648. Four other towns have builtor are building municipal lodging-houses for which no details areavailable. The other municipal dwellings erected are summarizedas follows:—

Kind of Dwelling. No. of Dwellings. No. of Rooms.
Blocks 12,165 27,523
Tenement Houses 2,507 6,068
Cottage flats 2,004 5,747
Cottages 3,830 17,611
  Total 20,506 56,949

It appears from these figures that municipal building has providedfor a smaller number of persons in the whole of the United Kingdomthan private enterprise in London alone. The principal townswhich have erected dwellings in blocks are London (7786), Glasgow(2300), Edinburgh (596), Liverpool (501), Dublin (460) and Manchester(420). The great majority of such dwellings contain eithertwo or three rooms. Tenement houses have been built in Liverpool(1424), Manchester (308), Sheffield (192), Aberdeen (128), and inseven other towns on a small scale. Such tenements are generallysomewhat larger than those built in blocks; the proportion of three- andfour-roomed dwellings is higher and only a small number consistof a single room. Cottage flats have been built in Dublin (528),West Ham (401), Battersea (320), Plymouth (238), East Ham (212),and on a small scale in Liverpool, Birmingham, Newcastle and sevenother places. The majority of the cottage flats contain three ormore rooms, a considerable proportion have four rooms. Cottages have been built in 67 places, chiefly small towns and suburbandistricts. Of the large towns which have adopted this class ofdwellings Salford stands first with 633 cottages; three Londonboroughs, all on the south side of the Thames, have built 234;Manchester has 228, Sheffield 173, Huddersfield 157, Birmingham103. The number of rooms in municipal cottages ranges fromthree to eight, but the great majority of these dwellings have fouror five rooms.

Some further details of municipal housing in particular towns areof interest. In London, the work of the London County Councildown to March 31, 1908, not including three lodging-homes containing1845 cubicles, is given in the official volume of London Statistics,published by the Council, as follows:—

Buildings Erected and in Course of Erection.
No. of
Dwellings.
No. of
Rooms.
Cost of Land
and Building.
No. of Persons
in Occupation.
8,373 22,939 £2,438,263 26,687

With regard to the cost, it is to be noted that the actual cost of theland purchased for improvement schemes was very much greaterthan that stated, having been written down to an arbitrary figurecalled “housing valuation.” The financial accounts of L.C.C.dwellings for the year ending March 31, 1908, are thus summarized:—

London County Council Dwellings, Accounts 1907–1908.
Gross
Rental.
Deductions for
Empties, &c.
Net Receipts. Expenditure
including
Interest.
Net
Returns.
£180,169 £19,455 £160,714 £157,141 £3,573

It appears from this that if the actual commercial cost of the landwere taken the housing of the Council would be run at a considerableannual loss. The occupations of the tenants are stated in thefollowing proportions: labourers 789, clerks 312, policemen 251,shop assistants 202, warehousemen 183, printers 182, charwomen182, tailors 155, cabinetmakers 146, canvassers 122, cigarettemakers 118, widows 116, tram drivers 110, postmen 107, packers 97,engineers 87, dressmakers 41, coachmen 31, motormen 26, milliners19. These proportional figures show that though a considerablenumber of labourers have been housed, the great majority of theoccupants of London municipal dwellings are of a superior class.The mean weekly rent in London County Council dwellings is2s. 101/2d. per room against 2s. 4d. in dwellings erected by otheragencies. The most important feature of the County Council’spolicy in recent years has been the acquisition of suburban sites forthe erection of cottages. There are four such sites, two on thesouth, one on the north and one on the west side of London; thetotal area is 349 acres, and the total accommodation contemplatedis for 66,000 persons at an estimated cost of £3,105,840; the presentaccommodation is for about 8000. In addition to the housingprovided by the County Council, fourteen London Borough Councilsand the City Corporation had at the beginning of 1909 erected oradapted 3136 dwellings containing 7999 rooms.

In Liverpool, down to 1907, about £920,000 had been spent inclearing insanitary areas and building new dwellings; the demolitionof about 8000 houses and purchase of land cost about£500,000; and the erection of 2046 dwellings, containing 4961rooms, cost about £350,000. The size of the dwellings and thenumber of each class are: 1 room, 193; 2 rooms, 965; 3 rooms,719; 4 rooms, 167. The great majority are in tenement houses ofthree storeys. The mean weekly rent is 1s. 61/2d. per room, but alarge number are let at less. The net return on the total outlay isjust over 1%, on the building outlay it is 22/3%. The principalclasses of persons occupying the dwellings are labourers 675, carters120, charwomen 103, firemen 93, porters 80, hawkers 64, sailors 45,scavengers 40. These all belong to the poorest classes, living bycasual or irregular work. Liverpool has, in fact, succeeded morethan any other town in providing municipal dwellings in which thereally poor can afford to live.

In Manchester 956 dwellings have been built at a total cost forbuilding and improvement of £451,932; of the whole number 420are in blocks, 308 in tenement houses and 228 in cottages. Therents are much higher than in Liverpool; in the tenement housesthe mean weekly rent is about 6d. per room more than in Liverpool.The gross profit on the block dwellings is 11/3% on the capital outlay,on the tenement houses 3%, on the cottages 22/3%. “The totalloss during the last seven to ten years, including loan charges, hasamounted to about £54,240” (Thompson).

In Glasgow the corporation has built under improvement schemes2280 new dwellings containing 4013 rooms and 241 shops. Thedwellings, which are all in blocks and centrally situated, are occupiedchiefly by artisans; only 28% have been reserved for the poorestclass of tenants. The total amount taken from the rates on thisaccount in 30 years is £600,000. Dwellings valued at £400,000 forbuilding and £300,000 for land give a net return of 3.06% on outlay;dwellings valued at £280,000 for land and building return3.03% on outlay; leaving the sinking fund charges to be defrayedout of rates.

In Edinburgh insanitary areas have been bought for £107,023and new dwellings containing 1032 rooms have been built for £87,970.Nearly all the dwellings are of one or two rooms only. The rentscharged average about 2s. a week per room; actual rents receivedaverage 1s. 4d. per room and they have to be subsidized out of therates to the extent of 2s. 3d. per room to meet the cost of site.

In Dublin provision has been or was in 1909 shortly to be madefor housing 5394 families or 19,000 persons; of which 1041 families,or about one-fifth, are housed by the Corporation, the rest bycompanies and private persons. Altogether it was estimated that£500,000 would be spent under the act of 1890. Fifteen streets,containing 1665 houses, have been declared unhealthy areas by themedical officer, and between 1879 and 1909 more than 3000 houseswere closed as unfit for habitation.

Co-operative Building.—Municipal and philanthropic housing by nomeans exhaust the efforts that have been made to provide working-classdwellings outside the ordinary building market. Their specialfunction has been to substitute better dwellings for pre-existingbad ones, which is the most costly and difficult, as well as the mosturgent, part of the problem in old towns. But in the provision ofnew dwellings alone they have been far surpassed by organized self-helpin different forms. Down to 1906 there had been built 46,707houses by 413 co–operative societies at a cost of nearly £10,000,000.They are most numerous in the manufacturing towns and particularlyin the north-western district of England. Of the wholenumber 8530 were owned by the societies which built them; 5577had been sold to members, and 32,600 had been built by memberson money lent by the societies. These figures do not include theparticular form of co-operative building known as co-partnershiphousing, which will be mentioned later on, or the operations of theso-called building societies, which are really companies lendingmoney to persons on mortgage for the purpose of building. Thedifference between them and the co-operative societies which dothe same thing is that the latter retain the element of co-operationby lending only to their own members, whereas the building societiesdeal in the open market. Their operations are on an immensescale; at the end of 1908 the invested funds of the registered buildingsocieties exceeded £72,000,000. An agency working on thisscale, which far exceeds the operations of all the others put together,is obviously an important factor in housing. The number of housesbuilt must help to relieve congestion, and since they are built tosuit the owners or tenants they cannot be of the worst class. Theyalso represent a form of thrift, and deserve notice on that account.

The Small Dwellings Acquisition Act of 1899, which has notpreviously been mentioned, was intended to facilitate the buildingor purchase of small houses by their tenants by means of loansadvanced by local authorities. Down to 1906 about £82,000 hadbeen so advanced by 5 county boroughs, 17 urban councils and 1rural district council.

Housing by Employers.—No comprehensive information is availableon this head, but it has not been an important factor in towns,being chiefly confined to agricultural, mining and suburban manufacturingdistricts. The former two belong to the subject of RuralHousing, which is separately discussed below; the third has aninterest of its own on account of its connexion with “model settlements.”The building of houses for their workpeople by industrialemployers has never been widely adopted in this country, but ithas attracted considerable attention at two different periods. SirTitus Salt was a pioneer in this direction, when he built his woollenmills at Saltaire, on the outskirts of Bradford, and housed his workpeopleon the spot. That plan was maintained by his successors,who still own some 900 excellent and cheap cottages, and wasadopted by a few other manufacturers in the same neighbourhood.Saltaire was a model settlement with many institutions for thebenefit of the mill-hands, and as such it attracted much attention;but the example was not generally followed, and the interest lapsed.Recently it has been revived by the model settlements at PortSunlight, near Liverpool, started about 1888, Bournville nearBirmingham (1895), and Earswick, near York (1904), which are of amuch more elaborate character. Elsewhere, employers setting downworks in some new locality where no provision existed, have had tobuild houses for their workmen; but they have done so in a plainway, and this sort of housing has not assumed large proportions.

Conditions in 1909.—It has been said above that great improvementshave been effected, and of that there is no doubt at all.Both quantity and quality are more satisfactory than they were,though both are still defective. The conditions vary greatlyin different places, and no general indictment can be sustained.The common practice of citing some exceptionally bad cases,and by tacit inference generalizing from them to the wholecountry, is in nothing more misleading than in the matter ofhousing. Local differences are due to several causes—age, population, occupations and means of the people, public opinionand municipal energy. The first three chiefly determine thedifficulty and extent of the problem, the last two influence itstreatment. The difficulty is greatest in towns which are old,have large populations and a high percentage of poor. Suchpre-eminently are the large seaports, where much casual labouris employed. London, Liverpool, Glasgow, the Tyne, Hull,Sunderland are examples. Old inland towns having a largetrading as well as an industrial element present the same features.Such are Manchester, Birmingham, Leeds, Sheffield and Bradford.In all these, and some others like them, the past has left a heavylegacy of bad housing by malconstruction and dilapidation,which has been increased by growth of population and overcrowding.They have attacked it with varying degrees ofenergy according to the prevalent local spirit and with varyingresults.

Overcrowding.—The one condition which permits of preciseand comprehensive statement is overcrowding. A standardhas been officially adopted in England based on the number ofpersons to a room in each dwelling; and the facts in relationto this standard are embodied in the census returns. It is amuch better criterion than that of “density” or number ofpersons per acre, which is very deceptive; for an apparentlylow density may conceal much overcrowding within walls andan apparently high one may be comparatively guiltless. Theroom-density is the important thing in actual life. Some lightis also thrown on this question by the number of rooms containedin each dwelling, and that is also given in the census. Thestandard of overcrowding is more than two persons to a room.In 1901 there were in England and Wales 2,667,506 personsor 8.2% of the population living in a state of overcrowdingaccording to this definition. Their distribution is extremelyirregular and capricious. In rural districts the proportion wasonly 5.8%, in urban districts 8.9%; but these summaryfigures give no idea of the actual state of things in differentlocalities. In both rural districts and in towns the proportionof overcrowding varies in different localities from less than 1%to over 30% of the population. The towns are the most importantand we shall confine attention chiefly to them. A listof 84 having a population of 50,000 and upwards, exclusive ofLondon, is given by Mr Dewsnup. The overcrowding rangesfrom 34.54% in Gateshead and 32.42% in South Shields to0.97% in Northampton and 0.62% in Bournemouth. Of thewhole number exactly one-half have less than 5%; 15 have lessthan 2% and 22 have 10% or more. Neither size nor characterhas much to do with the variation. Bournemouth, at the bottomof the list with 0.62%, is a residential place and health resortwith a population of about 50,000; so is Tynemouth, which isnearly at the top, with 30.71%. The two largest towns, Liverpooland Manchester, are 26th and 32nd on the list, with only 7.94%and 6.28% respectively, or considerably less than the average;and on the other hand none of the first 17 towns with the highestproportion of overcrowding are of the largest size. Again, withregard to character, Leicester and Northampton, which arealmost at the bottom of the list, with 1.04% and 0.97% respectively,are both purely industrial towns. The most striking factsare that the six towns, which alone have more than 20% ofovercrowding, namely Gateshead (34.5), South Shields (32.4),Tynemouth (30.7), Newcastle (30.4), Sunderland (30.10),Plymouth (20.1) are all old seaports, that four of them at thehead of the list are on the Tyne and the fifth on the Wear.This points strongly to special local conditions and it is borne outby the facts with regard to rural districts. Northumberland andDurham show a great excess of overcrowding over other counties;and some of their rural districts even surpass any of the towns.The highest of all is the district of Tynemouth, with 38.18% ofovercrowding. The explanation lies in a special combinationof large families and small houses prevalent in this area. Allthe rural districts are seats of coal-mining, and miners are themost prolific section of the population. They also live in smallhouses of a traditional and antiquated character, often of onestorey only or built back to back. Many are built by collieryproprietors. Large families and small houses also prevail in thetowns. Some of them contain coal-pits and the rest of theirindustrial population is engaged chiefly in engineering andshipbuilding works, occupations also usually associated with ahigh birth-rate. The men live as near their work as possibleand the practice of living in flats or occupying part of a houseprevails extensively.

In London the number of persons living in overcrowdedconditions in 1901 was 726,096 or 16.0% of the population.The proportion varied from 2.6% in Lewisham to 35.2% inFinsbury, but in 23 out of the 29 boroughs into which the countyis divided it exceeded the urban mean for the whole country,and in 9 boroughs having an aggregate population of 1,430,000it was more than double the mean. Conditions in London areevidently untypical of English towns.

In the light of the census figures it is clear that no largeproportion of the English industrial population is living underconditions of serious overcrowding, outside the special districtsmentioned and that the expression “house famine” cannot beproperly applied to England or English towns in general. In theHouse of Commons, on the 16th of August 1909, the president ofthe Local Government Board, Mr John Burns, gave a list of thenumber of unoccupied houses and tenements in each of theLondon boroughs and in the eight largest provincial towns,including Glasgow; the total was 104,107. By a furtheranalysis of the census returns Mr Dewsnup shows that a greatdeal of the overcrowding is of a comparatively mild characterand that it is due to a relatively small excess of population.Bradford, for instance, is credited with 40,896 overcrowdedpersons, representing the high percentage of 14.61 of thepopulation; but in the case of nearly 20,000 the excess over thestandard is very slight, and the proportion of gross overcrowdingcomes down to 7.55%. Moreover, this serious overcrowdingis produced by no more than 2.79 of the population, so thatits cure presents no insuperable difficulty. The argumentis confirmed by the very substantial diminution which actuallytook place between 1891 and 1901. The facts are so strikingthat they deserve to be presented in tabular form:—

Percentage of Population Overcrowded.
  1891 1901
England and Wales  11.23 8.20
Gateshead 40.78 34.54
Newcastle 35.08 30.47
Sunderland 32.85 30.10
Plymouth 26.27 20.19
Halifax 21.31 14.49
Bradford 20.61 14.61
Huddersfield 19.89 12.88
London 19.70 16.01
Leeds 16.46 10.08
St Helens 15.72 10.86
Birmingham 14.27 10.32
Burnley 12.74 7.14
Sheffield 11.58 9.50
Bolton 11.22 6.50
Liverpool 10.96 7.94
Oldham 10.13 7.42
Salford 9.39 7.54
West Ham 9.34 9.27
Wolverhampton 9.31 4.67
Swansea 9.25 5.57
Stockport 8.50 4.98
Manchester 8.25 6.28
Bristol 8.03 3.55
Hull 7.86 6.12
Blackburn 7.05 3.92
Birkenhead 6.80 5.02
Norwich 4.91 3.34
Brighton 4.56 3.07
Cardiff 4.31 2.92
Preston 4.13 2.64
Nottingham 3.62 3.65
Croydon 2.76 2.74
Derby 2.69 1.18
Leicester 2.22 1.04
Portsmouth 1.74 1.19

To what is this remarkable movement due? It is far toogeneral to be attributed to the operation of the Housing Acts;for, though they have helped in some cases, a great diminutionhas occurred in many places in which no use has been made ofthem. Towns of all kinds and in all parts of the country exhibitthe same movement in some degree; those which had littleand those which had much overcrowding, the worst and thebest. In London the percentage fell by 3.7, and the numberof persons overcrowded was reduced by 103,669 in spite of anincrease of population of 324,798. In Gateshead a fall of 6.2%,in Newcastle one of 4.6% took place; while at the other endof the scale Leicester and Derby reduced their already verylow proportions by more than one-half. Nottingham is theonly exception in the whole list. And in 28 out of the 35 townsthe decrease of overcrowding was absolute as well as relativein spite of a large increase of population. London has beencited. The other large towns may be tabulated with it, thus:—

Town. Increase of
Population.
Decrease of
Overcrowded
Persons.
London 324,898 103,669
Liverpool 166,978 2,381
Manchester 38,504 7,545
Birmingham  44,091 14,290
Leeds 61,463 17,252
Sheffield 56,550 1,388
Bristol 107,367 6,105
Bradford 63,406 3,696

The very divergencies make the uniform diminution of overcrowdingthe more remarkable. The large increase of populationin Liverpool and Bristol no doubt means extension of boundaries,which might have the effect of reducing the proportions of overcrowding,but it cannot account for the actual decrease ofovercrowded persons. The change seems to be due to threefactors all of which have been in general operation though invarying degrees. They are (1) the centrifugal movement promotedby improved locomotive facilities, (2) the decliningbirth-rate, (3) public health administration. (1) The first is themost important and the chief element has been tramways, ofwhich a great extension accompanied by electrification tookplace in the decade. Thus the process of urbanization has beenmodified by one of suburbanization. Bristol is a prominentcase; its overcrowding has been reduced by more than one-halfwithout any large and costly municipal interference, mainlythrough the operation of ordinary economic forces. Tramwayshave made the outskirts accessible and builders haveutilized the opportunity. They have built goodhouses, too, under supervision, and Bristol, thoughan old seaport and industrial town with muchpoverty, has the lowest general death-rate andthe lowest infantile death-rate of all the greattowns. (2) The birth-rate and the size of familiesare conditions which affect overcrowding in avery marked degree, though no attention is paidto them in that connexion. The case of themining districts and the towns on the Tyne hasbeen mentioned above; the same thing is seenin London, where all the most overcrowded districts(Finsbury, Stepney, Shoreditch and BethnalGreen) have high birth-rates, ranging from 31.3 to 36.4 per1000 in 1902–1906. The necessity imposed on poor parentsof putting several children into a cheap and therefore smalldwelling accounts for a large proportion of overcrowding, whichautomatically diminishes with a falling birth-rate. The ultimateadvantage of this method of reducing overcrowding is a questionon which opinions may differ, but there is no doubt about thefact. (3) Public health administration is the third generalcause; it attracts no notice and works very gradually, but itdoes work. The last annual report (for 1907) of the medicalofficer to the London County Council says of overcrowding:“There is reason for thinking that in recent years greaterattention has been paid by sanitary authorities to the abatementof the nuisance, and Dr Newman states that in Finsbury therehas been an enormous reduction in overcrowding, the reductionhaving been effected mainly in the years 1901–1905.” Themedical officers of the metropolitan boroughs reported in 19072613 dwellings overcrowded in 23 boroughs and 3216 suchdwellings remedied in 27 boroughs. It should not be forgottenthat a good deal of overcrowding is voluntary. Families whichhave not enough room for their own members nevertheless takein lodgers; and in some places, of which London is the mostconspicuous but not the only example, foreigners herd togetherthickly in a very small space.

The improvement shown by the statistics of overcrowding isconfirmed by those relating to the size of dwellings. Between1891 and 1901 the percentage of the population living in verysmall dwellings appreciably diminished thus—in 1-roomeddwellings, from 2.2 to 1.6%; in 2-roomed dwellings, from 8.3to 6.6%; in 3-roomed dwellings, from 11.1 to 9.8%; while theproportion living in dwellings of 5 rooms and upwards increasedfrom 54.9 to 60.1%. This again is referable to the suburbanmovement and a higher standard of requirements. Six-roomedhouses with a bathroom tend to replace the old four-roomed type.The general report accompanying the census says: “Howeverthe tenement figures for England and Wales are compared it isimpossible to avoid the conclusion that the comparison affordssatisfactory evidence of distinct improvement in the housing ofthe people during the ten years 1891–1901.” In short, theproblem of quantity is only acute in a few places and steadilybecoming less so.

The foregoing facts apply only to England and Wales. In Scotlandthe state of things is much less satisfactory. No statistics of overcrowdingare available, but the following comparative table showshow different the housing conditions are in the two countries:—

Size of Dwellings, England and Scotland, 1901.
Dwelling. Percentage of Population.
England. Scotland.
1 room 1.6 11.1
2 rooms 6.6 39.5
3 rooms 9.8 19.9
4 rooms 21.9 9.1
5 rooms and over  60.1 20.4

Over 50% of the population of Scotland live in tenements of oneor two rooms; only 8.2% in England. A comparison of the largesttowns in the two countries gives the following result:—

Percentage of Population.
Scotland. England.
Town. 1 Room. 2 Rooms. Town. 1 Room. 2 Rooms.
Glasgow 16.2 38.9 London 6.7 15.5
Edinburgh 8.9 32.4 Liverpool 2.7 5.9
Dundee 11.3 51.7 Manchester 0.8 4.01
Aberdeen 6.1 33.2 Birmingham  0.3 2.4
Greenock 11.3 47.6 Sheffield 0.4 4.0
Kilmarnock  18.9 43.3 Bristol 1.6 5.7
Mean 12.7 42.4 Mean 1.8 6.7

The conditions in Scottish towns where very tall tenement housesare common, resemble those in other countries, in which overcrowdingis far greater than in England. All these matters are comparative,and the superiority of conditions in England ought to be recognized.Yet, in Scotland, too, great improvements have been effected. In1861 there were 25,959 houses without windows; in 1901 only 130.These facts throw light on the long standing of the housing question,the change of standard and the improvement effected.

In Ireland there is more overcrowding than in England, thoughprobably less than in Scotland, with the possible exception ofDublin, which has a larger proportion of one-roomed dwellings thanany Scottish town, namely, 24.7%. The percentage of populationliving in overcrowded conditions in the principal towns is—Dublin40.6, Limerick 31.7, Cork 23.4, Waterford 20.6, Londonderry 16.7,Belfast 8.2.

Sanitary Conditions.—With regard to the quality of existinghousing reference has already been made to the effect of thePublic Health Acts and the general improvement in sanitation.The only numerical measure is afforded by the death-rates,which have fallen in England from 20.9 per 1000 in 1871–1875 to15.4 per 1000 in 1903–1907 and in the United Kingdom from21.3 to 15.7 per 1000 in the same period. The condition of thedwelling must be credited with a considerable share in this fall.There have, in fact, been great changes and all in the directionof improvement. The rise and development of sanitation, ofhouse and main drainage and sewage disposal, the purification ofwater and provision of a constant service in the house, theremoval of refuse, the segregation of infectious illness, sanitaryinspection—all these, apart from the demolition of the worsthousing and the provision of better, have raised the generalhealthiness of the dwellings of the people. In face of these factsand of the vital statistics, to say that the people are physicallydeteriorating through the influence of bad housing is to talkobvious nonsense, for all conditions have been improving formore than a generation. If physical deterioration is going on,of which there is no proof, either it is not caused by bad housingor there is less than there was. Deterioration may be caused bythe continued process of urbanization and the congregating of anever larger proportion of the population in towns; but that is adifferent question. If the town has any injurious influence it isnot due to the sanitary condition of the houses, which is in generalsuperior to that of houses in the country, but to the habits andoccupations of the people or to the atmosphere and the mereaggregation. But much misapprehension prevails with regard totowns. The most distinctive and the most valuable feature ofEnglish housing is the general predominance of the small house orcottage occupied by a single family. Only in London and a fewother towns do blocks of large tenement houses of the continentaltype exist, and even there they are comparatively few. InEngland and Wales 84% of the population live in dwellings of4 rooms and upwards, which means broadly separate houses.Now the prevalence of small houses involves spreading out andthe covering of much ground with many little streets, whichproduce a monotonous effect; a smoky atmosphere makes themgrimy and dull skies contribute to the general dinginess. Thewhole presents to the eye a vast area of dreary meanness andmonotony. Thus the best feature of English national housingturns to its apparent disadvantage and the impression is gainedby superficial observers that the bulk of our working-classpopulations lives in “slums.” The word “slum” has no precisemeaning, but if it implies serious sanitary defects it is not applicableto most of our town housing. There are real slums still, butthe bulk of the working class population do not live in them; theylive in small houses, often of a mean and dingy exterior but inessential respects more sanitary than the large and often handsomeblocks to be seen in foreign towns, which are not put downas slums because they do not look dirty. A smoky atmosphere isinjurious to health, but it must be distinguished from defects ofhousing. Ideal houses in a smoky place soon look bad; inferiorones in a clean air look brighter and deceive the eye. The worstof the old housing has disappeared; the filthy, dilapidated, airlessand sunless rookeries—the real slums—and the undergrounddwellings have been swept away in most cases, and what remainsof them is not so bad as what has gone. But reform has beenvery regularly applied. Some towns have done much, otherslittle. The large towns, in which the evil was most intense andmost conspicuous in bulk, have as a class done far more thansmaller ones in which the need perhaps was less great, but inwhich also a less healthy public spirit prevailed. The worsthousing conditions to-day are probably to be found in old townsof small and medium size, in which the ratepayers have a greatdisinclination to spend money on anything, and the control oflocal affairs is apt to be in the hands of the owners of the mostinsanitary property. Nor is this state of things altogether confinedto old places. Some of recent growth have been allowed,for the same reason, to spring up and develop without any regardto sanitary principles or the requirements of public health.There is therefore abundant scope for further reform and in nota few cases urgent need of it. On the other hand, we have anumber of towns, particularly manufacturing towns, both largeand small in the midlands and the north of England, which havealready reached a good general standard of housing in all essentialrequirements, and only need the regular and steady exercise ofvigilance by the public health service to remove such defects asstill remain or may reveal themselves with the lapse of time.

Rents.—Rent is a matter of great importance from every pointof view, and that is now being realized. A quantity of officialinformation on the subject has been collected and made availableby an elaborate inquiry ordered by the Board of Trade in 1905 andpublished in 1908 (Cd. 3864). It relates to working class dwellingsin the principal industrial towns in the United Kingdom, 94 in all:namely, 77 in England and Wales, 11 in Scotland and 6 in Ireland.The following tables give in a condensed form the chief statisticalresults obtained in October 1905:—

Predominant Range of Weekly Rents.

  England and Wales. Scotland. Ireland.
London. Provincial
towns.
One room .. .. 2/- to 2/6 1/6 to 2/6
Two rooms 4/6 to 7/6 3/- to 3/6 3/10 to 4/3 2/6 to 3/6
Three rooms  6/- to 9/- 3/9 to 4/6 5/2 to 6/5 4/- to 5/-
Four rooms 7/6 to 10/6 4/6 to 5/6 .. 5/6 to 6/9
Five rooms 9/- to 13/– 5/6 to 6/6 .. ..
Six rooms 10/6 to 15/6 6/6 to 7/9 .. ..

Rents are lowest in Ireland and next lowest in English provincialtowns, considerably higher in Scotland and highest of all in London,for which further special details are given. It is divided into threezones (1) central, (2) middle, (3) outer, which have the followingmean weekly rents:—

London Mean Weekly Rents.
  Zone.
Central. Middle. Outer.
One room 4/6 3/9 ..
Two rooms 7/- 6/- ..
Three rooms 8/9 7/6 6/6
Four rooms .. 9/- 7/9
Five rooms .. 11/- 9/6
Six rooms .. 13/- 11/-

In central London—which extends to Stepney in the East, Lambethm the South, Islington in the North, and includes Westminster,Holborn, Finsbury, Marylebone, Shoreditch, most of Bethnal Green,Southwark and Bermondsey—the rent of a single room may beas high as 6s. or even 6s. 6d. (Holborn) a week. It is here thatovercrowding is greatest, and block-tenements, philanthropic andmunicipal, most numerous. The rentals of the block dwellings havenot been taken into account in the foregoing official statistics;they range as follows: 1 room, 2s. 6d. to 5s.; 2 rooms, 5s. to 8s.;three rooms, 6s. 6d. to 11s. The lowest rent for which a singleroom can be obtained in this area is 2s. 6d. a week. In no Englishtown are rents nearly so high as in London. If 100 is taken as theindex number for rent in London the nearest towns to it (Croydonand Plymouth) only reach 81, and one town on the list (Macclesfield)is as low as 32. The index number of twenty-one towns out of thewhole is 50 or under, and these include a number of importantindustrial centres—Hull, Leicester, Blackburn, Northampton,Warrington, Coventry, Crewe and others. The index numbers ofthe great towns are: Liverpool 65, Manchester and Salford 62,Birmingham 59, Leeds 56, Sheffield 55, Bristol 53, Bradford 59,Hull 48; that is to say the level of rents in these towns is littlemore than half that in London. This is one more proof of the untypicalcharacter of London, and of the fallacy of generalizing fromit to the rest of the country. Even in the overcrowded towns onTyneside rents do not run to three-fourths of the London level.When the towns are divided into geographical groups the indexnumbers run thus: London 100, Northern Counties 62, Yorkshire56, Lancashire and Cheshire 54, Midlands 51, Eastern Counties 50,Southern Counties 61, Wales and Monmouth 60. Rents are alwayshighest in capitals, and Edinburgh complies with the rule; but it isvery slightly in advance of Glasgow, and in Scotland generally therange is much smaller than in England. Dublin, on the other hand,is differentiated from the other Irish towns as widely as Londonfrom English ones.

A general and progressive rise in rents has been taking place formany years. The following index numbers for the great towns are given in the second series of memoranda published by the Board ofTrade in 1904 (Cd. 1761):—

Relative Working-Class Rents.
188086.6189596.3
188590.11900100.0
189089.9

The tendency to rise is attributable to increased cost of labour,due to higher wages and less work, increased cost of materials andhigher rates. Weekly working-class rents generally include rateswhich are paid by the landlord. Housing reform has contributedto the rise, both directly and through the rates, on which it hasthrown a heavy burden in various ways. When slums are clearedaway and replaced by superior dwellings the new rents are generallyhigher than the old and this fact has proved a great difficulty. Mostof the improved housing is beyond the means of those who need itmost, and they seek other quarters resembling the old ones as nearlyas possible. The example of Liverpool, which has the largestproportion of casual and ill-paid labour of all the great towns, andhas been the most successful in providing new dwellings of a fairquality, centrally situated and not in blocks, at really low rates,shows that the problem is not insoluble; but as a rule too littleattention is paid to the question of rent in housing reform, especiallyin building undertaken by municipalities. It is not ignored, but theimportance attached to it by the poor is not realized. To them it isthe first consideration after four walls, a roof and a fire-place;and 6d. a week makes a vast difference in their calculations. Reformwhich aims at raising the lowest classes of tenants by improvingtheir dwellings defeats itself when it drives them away.

Rural Housing.—Little has hitherto been said about ruralhousing. It is of less importance than urban housing becauseit concerns a much smaller proportion of the population, andbecause in rural life the influence of inferior housing on health isoffset by other conditions; but it has recently attracted muchattention and was made the subject of inquiry by a Select Committeeof the House of Commons in 1906. The report laid stresschiefly on the inaction of local rural authorities under the PublicHealth and Housing Acts, and on various obstacles in the wayof improving existing houses and of providing more and betterones at rents which agricultural labourers can afford to pay.The available facts with regard to rural housing are scrappy andunsatisfactory. The word “rural” has no precise meaning andit includes several very different sections of the population; forinstance, the inhabitants of suburbs, mining villages and millvillages as well as the real agricultural population. Complaintis made of both the quantity and the quality of rural housing.With regard to quantity it is said that in spite of migration tothe towns there is a dearth of cottages through dilapidation anddemolition without rebuilding. That may happen in particularlocalities, but there is no evidence to support a general allegation.Inquiries issued by the Board of Trade to agricultural correspondentsbrought the following replies: insufficient 56, sufficient111, more than sufficient 32. Similar inquiries of land agents andowners resulted thus: insufficient 9, sufficient 11, more thansufficient 4, variable 6. From which it appears that insufficiencyexists but is not general. The official evidence with regard toovercrowding is that it is much less acute than in the towns.The proportion of the rural population in England living inovercrowded conditions in 1901 was 5.8%; if the rural miningdistricts, the exceptional overcrowding of which has been notedabove, be eliminated, the rest cannot be very bad. Moreover,the percentage has appreciably diminished; in 1891 it was8.46. The complaint of bad quality is better founded. Somelandowners take great pride in the state of their property, andexcellent cottages may be found in model villages and elsewherein many parts of the country; but much rural housing is of anextremely insanitary character. A good deal of evidence on thishead has of late years been published in the reports of medicalinspectors to the Local Government Board. And local authoritiesare very reluctant to set the law in motion against insanitarydwellings. On the other hand, they have in some cases hinderedand prevented building by too rigid insistence on by-laws,framed with a view to urban housing and quite unsuited to ruralconditions. A few rural authorities have taken action withregard to building schemes under Part III. of the Housing Act.A list of 31 in 17 counties is given in “Housing up to Date”; 13applications were refused and 13 granted by the respective countycouncils and others were dropped. Details are given by thesame authority of 54 houses built by 17 rural district councils.Public action may thus be said to amount to nothing at all.Landowners, however, have borrowed under the Improvementsof Lands Acts upwards of £1,250,000 for building labourers’cottages; and this is probably only a fraction of the amountspent privately.

In Ireland a special condition of affairs exists. A seriesof about a dozen acts, dating from 1881 and culminating in theLabourers (Ireland) Act of 1906, have been passed for promotingthe provision of labourers’ cottages; and under them 20,634cottages had been built and some thousands more authorizedprevious to the act of 1906, which extended the pre-existingfacilities. The principle is that of the English Housing Actsapplied to rural districts, but the procedure is simpler andquicker. The law provides that a representation may be madeto the local authority by three ratepayers or resident labourersthat “the existing house accommodation for agriculturallabourers and their families is deficient having regard to theordinary requirements of the district, or is unfit for humanhabitation owing to dilapidation, want of air, light, ventilationor other convenience or to any other sanitary defects,” whereuponthe local authority shall make an improvement scheme. It mayalso initiate a scheme without representation, or the LocalGovernment Board may do so in default of the local authority.The scheme is published, an inquiry held, notice given and anorder made with very much less delay and expense than underthe English law. Land is purchased by agreement, or compulsorilyand the money for land and building raised by loan.Loans amounting to about 31/2 millions sterling had been raiseddown to 1906. The great majority of the cottages built are inMünster and Leinster. They must have at least 2 bedroomsand a kitchen, and the habitable rooms must be 8 ft. high. Oneof the most remarkable features is the low cost—about £150—atwhich these cottages have been built, including land and theexpenses of procedure.

Recent Developments.—It is clear from a general review ofthe subject that the problem of housing the working classes ina satisfactory manner has proved more complex than was atone time realized. Experience has falsified hopes and led to achange of attitude. It is seen that there are limits to drasticinterference with the normal play of economic forces and tomunicipal action on a large and ambitious scale. A reactionhas set in against it. At the same time the problem is beingattacked on other sides and from new points of departure.The tendency now is towards the more effectual application ofgradual methods of improvement, the utilization of other meansand the exercise of prevention in preference to cure. Undereach of these heads certain movements may be noted.

The most troublesome problem is the treatment of existingbad housing. In regard to this the policy of large improvementschemes under which extensive areas are bought up anddemolished has had its day, and is not likely to be revived to anyconsiderable extent. That is not only because it is extremelycostly but also because it has in the main done its work. Ithas done what could not have been done otherwise, and has sweptaway the worst of the old housing en masse. To call it a failurebecause it is costly and of limited application would be as great amistake as to regard it as a panacea. The procedure which seemsto be coming into favour in place of it is that adopted in Birminghamand advocated by Mr J. S. Nettlefold (Practical Housing)coupled with a more general and effective use of the PublicHealth Acts. The principle is improvement in detail effectedby pressure brought to bear on owners by public authority.The embodiment of this principle forms an important part of theHousing and Town Planning Bill introduced by the LocalGovernment Board in 1908, which contained clauses empoweringthe central authority to compel apathetic local authoritiesto do their duty in regard to the closing of unfit houses, andauthorizing local authorities both to issue closing orders andto serve notices on landlords requiring them “to execute suchworks as the local authority may specify as being necessary to make the house in all respects reasonably fit for human habitation.”

Among the other and less direct means to which attentionis being turned is the policy of getting people away from thetowns. The effect of improved travelling facilities in reducingurban overcrowding has been noted above. That object wasnot specifically contemplated in the building and electrificationof tramways, and in the development of other means of cheaplocal travel, but the beneficial effect has caused them to berecognized as an important factor in relation to housing and tobe more systematically applied in that connexion. A newerdeparture, however, is to encourage migration not to the outskirtsof towns but altogether into the country by facilitating theacquisition of small holdings of land. This has been done byprivate landowners in an experimental way for some years, andin 1907 the policy was embodied in the Small Holdings Act,which gives county and borough councils power to purchase orhire land compulsorily and let it in holdings of not more than50 acres or £50 annual value. Failing action on their part theBoard of Agriculture may frame schemes. Power is alsoconferred on the Board and on County Councils to establishco-operative agricultural societies and credit banks. Thesemeasures have been adopted from foreign countries, and particularlyfrom Denmark and Germany. A very large number ofapplications for holdings have been made under this act, but itis too early to state the effects. They will depend on the successof tenants in earning a livelihood by agricultural produce.

Another new and quite different departure is the attemptto establish a novel kind of town, called a “Garden City,”which shall combine the advantages of the town and the country.The principal points are the choice of a site, which must besufficiently convenient to enable industries to be carried on,yet with rural surroundings, the laying out of the ground insuch a way as to ensure plenty of open space and variety, theinsistence on building of a certain standard and the limitationof size. One has been established at Letchworth in Hertfordshire,34 m. from London, and so far seems to be prospering. It consistsof an area of 3800 acres, bought from the previous owners by acompany registered in 1903 and entitled First Garden City Ltd.,with a capital of £300,000 in £5 shares. The interest is limitedto a dividend of 5%, all further profits to be devoted to thebenefit of the town. The estate is divided into a central urbanarea of 1200 and a surrounding agricultural belt of 2600 acres.The town is planned for an eventual population of 30,000 andat present (1909) has about 5000. Some London printingworks and other small industrial establishments have beenplanted there, and a number of model cottages have been built.In this connexion another recent novelty has appeared in theshape of an exhibition of cottages. The idea, originated byMr St Loe Strachey, was to encourage the art of designing andbuilding cheap but good and convenient cottages, especiallyfor the country. Two exhibitions have been held at Letchworthin 1905 and 1907, and others at Sheffield (1907) and Newcastle(1908). The two latter were held on municipal land, and it isproposed by the National Housing Reform Council to hold oneevery year.

The “Garden City” has led to the “Garden Suburb,” anadaptation of the same idea to suburban areas. One wasopened near Hampstead Heath in 1907: it consists of 240 acres,of which 72 have been reserved for working-class cottages withgardens. These developments, with which may be associatedthe model industrial villages, mentioned above, at Bournville,Port Sunlight and Earswick, represent an aspiration towardsa higher standard of housing for families belonging to the upperranks of the working classes; and the same movement isdemonstrated in a still more interesting fashion by a particularform of co-operative activity known as Co-partnership Housing.The first complete example of this method of organization wasthe Ealing Tenants Limited, a society registered under theIndustrial and Provident Societies Act in 1901, though theTenant Co-operators Limited, formed in 1888, was a precursoron very nearly the same lines. The essential principle is self-helpapplied by combination to the provision of superior homes, andthe chief material feature is the building of houses which arenot only of good design and workmanship, but disposed on asystematic plan so as to utilize the ground to the best advantage.Land is bought and houses are built with combined capital towhich each tenant contributes a substantial share; the housesare let at rents which will return 5% on share capital and 4%on loan capital after defraying all expenses, and the surplusprofits are divided among the tenant members in proportionto the rents paid by them. Each tenant’s share of profits iscredited to him in shares until his share capital equals the valueof the house he occupies, after which it is paid in cash. Thereis thus common ownership of the whole group, which forms alittle community. This system has caught on in a remarkableway and has spread with great rapidity. In 1905 a centralorganizing body was formed called the Co-partnership HousingCouncil, for the purpose of promoting the formation of societiesand assisting them with advice; it is supported by voluntarycontributions. In 1909 twelve societies, including the originalTenant Co-operators, had been formed with a total investmentof £536,300. They are situated at Ealing, Letchworth, Sevenoaks,Leicester, Manchester, Hampstead (two), Harborne nearBirmingham, Fallings Park, Stoke-on-Trent, Wayford andDerwentwater. The rapidity with which the movement hasdeveloped and spread since the establishment of the Co-partnershipHousing Council indicates great vitality, and since it isbased on thoroughly sound lines it has probably a large future.It is the most interesting and in many respects the best of allrecent developments. The Report of the Select Committee onRural Housing mentioned above suggested that a Co-partnershipHousing Society should be formed in every county inEngland.

All the enterprises just described have one feature in common,namely, the laying out of sites on a plan which takes cognizanceof the future, secures a due proportion of open space, variety inthe arrangement of streets and the most advantageous dispositionof the houses and other buildings. They go beyond sanitaryrequirements and take account of higher needs. They havelent force to the advocacy of municipal “town-planning,” aspractised by several towns in Germany; and provision was madefor this procedure in the Housing and Town Planning Act of1909. The act contains clauses giving local authorities powerto prepare plans with reference to any land which appearslikely to be used for building purposes within or near their ownboundaries; and also to purchase land comprised in a town-planningscheme and either build on it themselves or let plotsfor building in accordance with the plan. The chief object is tosafeguard the future, prevent the repetition of past defectsand encourage a higher standard of housing.

These new developments represent an upward movement atthe higher end of the scale. They cater for the superior ranksof working classes, those who attach some importance tothe aesthetic and moral influence of pleasant and wholesomesurroundings, and are willing to sacrifice immediate gratificationsto a higher end. They embody an aspiration, set an example andexercise an educative influence. But they have nothing to dowith the housing of the really poor, which is the great difficulty;and their very attractiveness seems in some danger of drawingattention from it. Garden cities and suburbs will never housethe poor or even the bulk of our working class population, andit would be a pity if the somewhat sentimental popularity ofromantic schemes led to a distaste for the plodding effort whichalone can effect a real cure of deep-seated social evils of longstanding. All the new schemes and legislative proposals leaveuntouched the greatest difficulty of all, which lies not in thedwelling but in the tenant. It is comparatively easy to affordbetter opportunities to those who are willing to take advantageof them, but how to raise those who are not? The lesson taughtby Miss Octavia Hill’s classical experiment is, if not forgotten,certainly neglected in the presence of more showy efforts. Orperhaps it would be more true to say that half of it is neglected.Miss Hill was one of the pioneers in the comparatively modest method of improving and reconstructing bad houses, which, aswe have noted, is now being more generally recognized andpursued; but that was only half her work. She improved baddwellings and made them decent, but she also managed themon business lines, by a system of inspection and rent collectionwhich combined a judicious discipline with the stimulus of reward.This was done by means of personal service, which is the secretof all really effective work among the poor. Her words writtenyears ago remain true to-day: “The people’s homes are badpartly because they are badly built and arranged; they aretenfold worse because the tenants’ habits and lives are whatthey are. Transplant them to-morrow to healthy and commodioushomes and they will pollute and destroy them.”

The following is a list of the principal associations formed for thepromotion of housing reform: Mansion House Council on the Dwellingsof the Poor, Rural Housing and Sanitation Association, Workmen’sNational Housing Council, National Housing Reform Council,Co-partnership Tenants Housing Council. They are all of recentdate, except the first. There are also local associations at Liverpool,Oldham, Rochdale, York, Plymouth, and elsewhere.

Other Countries

At the International Housing Congress organized by theNational Housing Reform Council and held in London in 1907representatives were present from a number of foreign countriesand a good deal of information was collected and published inthe report of the Congress. Further detailed data have beensupplied by foreign correspondents to Mr W. Thompson andpublished in Housing up to Date. The more important factsrelating to the principal industrial countries are here condensedfrom this and other sources of information.

Austria.—An act for encouraging the building of cheap working-classdwellings was passed in 1902; it provides for exemption fromtaxes for 24 years of working-class dwellings which fulfil certainconditions including sanitary requirements, a minimum area perroom, minimum height, minimum door and window spaces, thicknessof walls, a maximum number of inhabitants (one to 4 sq. metres insleeping rooms), prohibition of lodgers, fixed rent and maximumprofit. The municipalities are the authority for administering sanitaryand housing laws; they have no power of compulsory purchase ofland without a special law. There is excessive overcrowding in thelarge towns; in Vienna (1900) 43% of the population live in dwellingsof 1 room or 1 room and a kitchen; in 60 provincial towns the proportionis 63%. Overcrowding is reckoned at more than 5 personsto a room and more than 9 to two rooms; the proportion of overcrowdedon this basis is nearly one-fifth in Vienna and one-fourth inthe provincial towns (Thompson).

Belgium.—An act was passed in 1889 instituting Comités dePatronage; since then other Acts relating to loan societies, and toinheritance and succession in the case of small properties. Comitésde Patronage are semi-official bodies, but without legal power, whosefunction it is to study the subject of housing, to report to localauthorities on existing conditions, to advise, to collect funds andpromote the provision of good houses by any means in their power.They influence public opinion and stimulate the activity of localauthorities which have the power to compel improvements and closedwellings unfit for habitation; they have led to the formation ofnumerous societies for erecting working-class dwellings. The latterare encouraged by the law in various ways; they are exempt fromthe payment of some government duties and partly exempt fromothers. Working men buying or building houses liable to registrationfees up to from 72 to 171 francs are exempted from personal, provincialand communal taxes. The National Savings Bank of Belgiumis empowered to lend money to working men for buying or buildinghouses and to insure the lives of those doing so, to preserve thehome for the family. In 1904 the number of workmen’s homesexempted from taxation was 164,387, and the amount of taxationremitted considerably exceeded 3 million francs; workmen hadacquired lands and houses valued at nearly £4,000,000; there were161 societies for building working-class dwellings; 30,000 workmenrepresenting a population of 150,000 had become owners of property;and 70,000 representing a population of 350,000 had availed themselvesof the law in obtaining exemptions and loans (O. Velghe).The foregoing results effected in 15 years are remarkable and indicatea great capacity for self-help on the part of Belgian workmen withsuitable and well-considered assistance. But this movement, incommon with those of a similar character in other countries, does nottouch the problem of housing the very poor. No statistics of overcrowdingare available, but the average number of persons to adwelling is over 5 for the whole country and nearly 9 in Brussels.The communal administrations are the authorities for health andhousing; they have power to abate nuisances but not to compellandowners to sell land for building, though they have the right todispossession for “public purposes.” No town has constructedquarters devoted entirely to working-class dwellings and only onecommune (St Giles) has built any. In towns the height of buildingsis regulated by the width of streets; generally it is the width plus6 metres. The height of rooms and thickness of walls are prescribedby local regulations but not the area of rooms. The housing difficultyhas been lessened in a notable degree by cheap transport facilities,including railroads, light railroads and tramways; a large proportionof the workpeople travel long distances to and from work. One-quartertravel on the State railways alone; fares are 1s. 6d. a weekfor a daily double journey of 20 m., 2s. for 44 m. and 2s. 6d. for66 m. The area of the labour market of Liége extends nearly toOstend and out of 5830 workmen travelling over 1000 live morethan 50 kilometres from Liége. Some journeys last 3 hours.

France.—The question of housing was publicly raised in Francequite as early as in England on grounds of public health in connexionwith the first visitation of cholera, and building societies wereformed as early as 1851, but little was done until after 1889, when theSociété Française des Habitations à Bon Marché was founded underthe inspiration of M. Siegfried. This led to the formation of severalsocieties, which increased rapidly after the passage of la loi Siegfriedin 1894, for promoting the provision of working-class dwellings. In1902 a Public Health Act and in 1906 a Housing of the WorkingClasses Act were passed, and these three enactments with regulationsmade in 1907 govern the procedure. The act of 1906 embodies theBelgian system of Comités de Patronage, of which at least one wasto be established in each department with grants in aid, and exemptionsfrom certain taxes of working-class dwellings fulfillingspecified conditions as to sanitation and rent. The law promotesthe formation of Housing Societies by granting various facilities forthe investment of money in building by public bodies and benevolentinstitutions by taking shares or by loans. Down to the end of 1906there had been lent for this purpose £233,000 by savings banks,£258,000 by the Caisse des Dépôts, and £14,000 by charitable institutions.The law does not authorize municipalities to buildhouses and none of the communes have acquired land for this purpose.Under the Public Health Act of 1902 towns can purchase landcompulsorily in connexion with unhealthy areas. The Public Healthand Housing Acts are administered by the local authority, whichmakes regulations for building and for laying out building land. Aminimum height of 2.6 metres and a minimum cubical content of25 cubic metres are prescribed for rooms; there are no regulationsfor thickness of walls. Housing societies are under the Ministry ofWorks and a Superior Housing Council, which is a central advisorybody. These societies are now numerous; there are 46 in Parisalone, but their operations are not on a large scale. One of themdeserves special notice on account of its special object. It is calledthe Société de logements pour familles nombreuses and it builds specialflats called maisons des enfants which are let at low rents only topersons with large families. In 1907 it had housed 168 families,averaging 6.8 persons, in two blocks at Belleville and Montmartre.The great defect in France is the large quantity of old, bad, insanitaryhousing. Real slums exist in all the old towns and in some of them,such as Marseilles and Lyons, on an extensive scale. Very littlehas hitherto been done to grapple with this difficulty. The standardof sanitation is altogether lower in France than in England, as isshown by the death-rates, and this holds good of the housing. Butconditions vary widely in different parts of the country. They arebetter, generally speaking, in the industrial towns of the north,which are largely Flemish and distinguished by the prevalence ofsmall houses after the English fashion, than in the central or southerndistricts where tall old tenement houses of six and seven storeysabound. There are no statistics and no standard of overcrowding;but the careful inquiry carried out by the Board of Trade and publishedin 1909 shows the extraordinary prevalence of tenements consistingof 1, 2 or 3 rooms. In 16 towns for which information was obtainedthe average proportion of dwellings containing less than 4 roomswas 75% of the whole; in some it was as high as 89% and in nonelower than 61%. In 8 towns, including Paris, the number of one-roomeddwellings was more than a quarter of the whole, and in twotowns (Brest and Fougères) it was more than half. Some correspondingstatistics for English and German towns are given below in thesection on Germany. According to the same report, the generalaccuracy of which has been confirmed by personal inquiries, madein 1909 by the writer in a number of towns, rents are decidedlylower in France. If the London level be taken as 100 that of Parisis only 78 and the other French towns are considerably lower, 21 outof 29 being less than half the London standard. A general comparisonbetween a number of English and French towns shows theaverage level of French rents to be less than three-fourths of Englishones. A noticeable feature of housing in France is the large numberof dwellings built by employers in recent years. The mining companies,particularly in the Pas de Calais, have built whole groups ofvillages; the railway companies and various manufacturers havealso done a great deal, chiefly in rural areas. Among the manufacturersMM. Schneider at Le Creusot and the textile mill-ownersin the Vosges are noticeable. The houses provided areof a charming type, white with red roofs; the rooms are of goodsize, the rents low, and a large garden is usually attached to everyhouse.

Germany.—In no country is the problem of housing more acute than in Germany, where the increase of population, the growth ofmanufacturing industry and the urbanization of the people haveproceeded at an exceptionally rapid pace in recent years and havecombined with increasing wealth and a rising standard of living toforce the question into prominence. Up to 1909 no uniform legislationfor the empire had been framed and no central authorityexisted for dealing with housing; but the several states have theirown public health and housing laws, and great activity has beendeveloped in various directions. The most general difficulty isdeficiency of quantity consequent on the rapid change in the distributionof the population. The proportion of the whole populationliving in the great towns increased from 7.2% to 16.2%, or morethan doubled between 1890 and 1900; in England it only increasedby about one-tenth. Slums are a much less conspicuous featurethan in England because of the comparatively recent developmentof German towns, but where old quarters exist on a large scale, asin Hamburg, the conditions are quite as bad as anything in Englishtowns, and call for similar measures. Public sanitation in Germanyis still as a whole less advanced than in England; but in somecases it is superior and in general it is coming up rapidly; theadministration of sanitary laws, as of others, is more effective anduniform, and less subject to evasion. This also contributes to thecomparative absence of slums. And there is a third factor whichhas perhaps the greatest influence of all, and that is the superiormanner in which German homes are kept. But the pressure ofinadequate quantity is urgent; it has caused high rents, overcrowding,and the development of large barrack or block dwellingswhich are becoming the prevailing type. At the same time it hasled to many and varied efforts to meet the difficulty. Isolatedattempts go back to an early date. For instance a building societywas formed in Berlin in 1849, Alfred Krupp began to build his“colonies” at Essen in 1863, Barmen started a society in 1871 andthere were other cases; but general attention seems first to havebeen drawn to the subject by the reforming efforts of Pastor Bodelschwinghat Bielefeld about 1884 in connexion with his Arbeiterheim.In short housing reform in Germany is really a matter of the last20 years. The first efficient by-laws for regulating building inBerlin were not adopted till 1887; the previous regulations datingfrom 1853 permitted many abuses and under them a great deal ofbad housing was constructed, especially after the establishmentof the empire and the beginning of the great development of thecapital.

The worst feature is the general prevalence of dwellings containinga very small number of rooms—from 1 to 3—and consequentovercrowding. The following figures are extracted from the Reportto the Board of Trade on Rents, Housing, &c., in Germany (1908,Cd. 4032). They indicate the proportion of dwellings containing1, 2 or 3 rooms, or (in a few cases) the proportion of the populationliving in such dwellings. The towns are those for which the informationis given. They are not selected as particularly badspecimens but as representative, and they include most of thecapitals and chief industrial centres. The figures relate to the year1900, except in a few cases, in which they are taken from a municipalhouse census in 1905.

Percentage of Dwellings or Population living in Dwellings containing
Town. 1 Room. 2 Rooms. 3 Rooms. Total under
4 Rooms.
Berlin  8.0 37.2 30.6 75.8
Aachen 13.7 32.0 21.9 67.6
Barmen (pop.)  1.5 24.3 28.8 54.6
Bremen  3.8(?) 26.8 26.1 56.7(?)
Breslau (pop.)  3.9 46.0 24.4 74.3
Chemnitz (pop.)  1.7 34.8 29.9 66.4
Dantzig  3.3 45.0 29.9 78.2
Dortmund  4.7 45.5 30.0 80.2
Dresden  0.8  3.5 27.8 32.1
Düsseldorf  5.0 26.4 22.7 54.1
Elberfeld  8.4(?) 36.9 21.7 67.0(?)
Essen  2.9 35.4 30.0 68.3
Hamburg  1.0  3.9 24.7 29.6
Königshütte (pop.)  10.0 60.4 16.8 87.2
Leipzig (pop.)  0.4  1.7 14.5 16.6
Mannheim  3.1 22.1 40.4 65.6
Munich (pop.)  4.6 24.1 28.4 57.1
Plauen (pop.)  1.3 14.2 21.8 36.3

The figures must be read with a certain amount of caution, as theyare not in every case compiled on a precisely uniform method withregard to inclusion of kitchens and attics. For this reason theposition of Bremen and Elberfeld is probably more unfavourablethan it ought to be. But broadly the table shows that in most ofthe large towns in Germany more than half, and in some cases morethan three-quarters of the dwellings have less than 4 rooms. Leipzigis the most striking exception. If working-class quarters alone aretaken it is found that dwellings of more than 3 rooms are so fewas to be negligible. In Stuttgart, where housing is very dear, thepercentages for working-class quarters are—1 room 21.0, 2 rooms51.8, 3 rooms 26.9; total under 4 rooms 98.7. Königshütte, the chiefcoal and iron centre in Silesia and a purely working-class town,shows the same state of things; 60% of the whole population livein dwellings of 2 rooms and 87% in less than four. It is interestingto compare English towns. The proportion of dwellings containingless than 4 rooms in London was (1901) 52.2%, in Berlin 75.8%;the proportion of the population living in such dwellings was—London38.7%, Berlin 71.5%. Not only is the proportion of smalldwellings very much higher in Berlin but the proportion of thepopulation living in them shows a far greater discrepancy. Thisindicates a much higher degree of overcrowding. The only pointin which Berlin has the advantage is the smaller number of single-roomdwellings. The proportions are London 14.7%, Berlin 8.0%.But it is to be observed that overcrowding is not so common in1–room dwellings, which are often occupied by a single person, asin those with 2 or 3 rooms, which are occupied by families, thoughprobably the most extreme cases of overcrowding occur in particular1–room dwellings. In the English county boroughs the proportion ofdwellings with less than 4 rooms was 24.0%, in other urban districts17.4, and in all urban areas including London 26.4%. When allallowance is made for minor errors and discrepancies it may bebroadly concluded that the proportion of small dwellings containingless than 4 rooms is at least twice as great in German as in Englishtowns, and that the conditions as to accommodation which inEngland prevail only in London are general in urban Germany.As a set-off German rooms are generally larger than English onesand in block dwellings there is often a little ante-room or landingwhich does not count but really increases the space.

The German census does not take cognisance of overcrowding andthere is no general official standard; but some towns have adopteda standard of their own, namely, six or more persons to 1 room andten or more to 2 rooms. In Breslau, which is one of the worsttowns, 17.5% of the population (53,000) of the “city” or innerring were overcrowded on this basis in 1900. In Barmen, which isnot one of the worst, 20% of the 2-roomed and 17% of the 3-roomeddwellings (together housing more than half the population) wereovercrowded according to the English standard. Overcrowdingand other bad conditions are worst in the basement or cellar dwellings,of which some towns have a very large number. In Breslau15,000 persons were living in 3853 such dwellings in 1900; inBerlin 91,426 persons were living in 24,088 basements. Some ofthese are free from objection, but 11,147, housing 38,663 persons,were situated in back buildings and unfit for habitation on accountof darkness, damp, dilapidation and the like. “Back” housesare a feature of old towns; they are houses which do not give onthe street but lie behind and are approached by a passage; they arewhat we call courts and quite as insanitary as anything of the kindin English towns.

With regard to rents the Board of Trade (London) Report givesthe following figures for Berlin and a number of other towns:—

No. of Rooms
per Dwelling.
Predominant Range of Weekly Rents.
Berlin. Other Towns.
2 rooms 5/- to 6/- 2/8 to 3/6
3 rooms 7/- to 9/3 3/6 to 4/9
4 rooms .. 4/3 to 6/-

Rents are higher in Berlin than in any other town, thoughStuttgart comes very near it. The following table of index numbersshows the relations of 32 towns to Berlin:—

Town. Index
Number.
Town. Index
Number.
Berlin 100 Nuremberg 53
Stuttgart 97 Aachen 53
Düsseldorf 79 Crefeld 52
Dortmund 68 Bremen 52
Anchaffenburg  67 Plauen 52
Hamburg 66 Leipzig 51
Mannheim 64 Dantzig 49
Königsberg 62 Mülhausen 48
Munich 63 Königshütte 47
Essen 62 Stettin 46
Solingen 61 Magdeburg 43
Bochum 57 Chemnitz 40
Elberfeld 57 Zwickau 38
Barmen 57 Brunswick 37
Remscheid 56 Stassfurt 33
Breslau 56 Oschersleben  28
Dresden 54    

Comparing rents in Germany and England, the Board of TradeReport gives the following table, to which the corresponding ratio

of French towns has been added.
No. of rooms. Predominant Weekly Rents. Ratio of
German to
English (100)
Ratio of
French to
English (100)
England. Germany.
2 rooms 3/– to 3/6 2/8 to 3/6  95 79
3 rooms 3/9 to 4/6 3/6 to 4/9 100 86
4 rooms 4/6 to 5/6 4/3 to 6/- 102 78

If the mean of the English and German figures be taken it showsa very slight difference in favour of Germany; the mean weekly rentper room being 1s. 5d. in England and 1s. 43/4d. in Germany. But inEngland rent usually includes local taxation (rates) whereas inGermany it does not; if this be added German rents are to Englishas 123 to 100, or nearly one-fourth more.

The statistics given above indicate a wide range of variation inthe conditions prevailing in different towns in Germany; and thatholds good with regard to improvements. The administration ofthe laws relating to public health and housing is in the hands of thelocal authorities. The public health service is generally efficientand sometimes very good. Increasing attention has been paid inrecent years to the sanitary inspection of houses and in some townsit is now thorough and systematic, but active efforts to deal withold and insanitary quarters en masse are isolated and exceptional.Hamburg is an instance; scared by the visitation of cholera in 1892the authorities put in hand an extensive improvement scheme onthe English plan at a cost of half a million sterling. But demolitionis exceptional; slums are usually subjected to supervision and arenot allowed to be in a state of dilapidation, and sometimes, as atMannheim, notices are served to abate overcrowding. In Municha policy of gradually buying up insanitary houses has been adopted.But improvement has principally been promoted by new buildingand the reduction of the population in old insanitary quarters, towhich cheap locomotive facilities have greatly contributed. Thegreat bulk of urban Germany is new, and the most valuable contributionmade by it to the housing question is the more effectivecontrol of new building and particularly the principle of town-planning,coupled with the purchase of neighbouring ground witha view to future extension. This policy is comparatively recent andstill very partially applied, but it is now rapidly extending. Ageneral act providing for the planning of streets was passed inPrussia in 1875 and still forms the basis of building legislation;but as noted above no effective by-laws were adopted even in Berlinuntil after 1887, and consequently a very faulty style of buildingwas adopted, especially in large blocks which conceal grave defectsbehind an imposing exterior. The Saxon towns have been conspicuouslysuccessful in regard to housing. Leipzig stands aloneamong German towns in having 83.4% of its population living indwellings of 4 rooms and upwards. Yet it is a great commercialcity, the fifth in the empire, with a population of upwards of half amillion. It also comes low on the rent table, having an index numberlittle more than half that of Berlin. All the Saxon towns are low,Chemnitz and Zwickau particularly so, and the position of Dresden,being a capital, is remarkable. More than two-thirds of the populationlive in dwellings of 4 rooms or more, and the rent index numberis only 54. In Saxony a general Building Act, especially providingfor town planning, was passed in 1900; and the Grand Duchy ofHesse, which alone among the German states has a governmentHousing Department, adopted a Housing of the Working ClassesAct in 1902. Other states have followed or are following and theair is full of movement. The distinctive features of urban housingreform in Germany are (1) the systematic planning of extensions,(2) purchase of ground by municipalities, (3) letting or sale of municipalland for building under prescribed conditions. Many of thegreat towns, including Berlin, Munich, Dresden, Leipzig, Cologne,Frankfort and Düsseldorf, are owners of land to a variable butsometimes large extent. This policy seems to have been originallyadopted on economic grounds and those municipalities which boughtor otherwise came into possession of town land at an early datederive a substantial revenue from it now, besides being in a positionto promote housing improvement. There is comparatively littlemunicipal building, and that as a rule only or principally for municipalservants, as at Düsseldorf, Mannheim and Nuremberg; butthere seems to be a tendency to venture further in this directionand some towns have built houses for letting. The municipalitiesgenerally sell or let their land, and the building agencies which enjoymost official favour are the societies “of public utility”; they areencouraged in every way and have greatly developed, particularlyin the Rhine province. Some are co-operative, others semi-philanthropicin that they aim at building good houses and limit theirprofits. In 1901 the Prussian Government issued an order urgingmunicipalities to support these societies by remitting the cost ofconstructing streets and sewers, placing the assistance of buildingofficials at their disposal, taking their shares, lending them moneyand becoming security for them. A great deal of public moneyhas been advanced to building societies, and one very importantsource of supply has been developed, since the Old Age and InfirmityInsurance Act of 1889, in the National Insurance Fundswhich invest their surplus capital in this way. Down to 1906 theBoards of insurance had lent £8,650,000 to societies for building;the Imperial Government had lent £1,250,000, thePrussian Government £1,825,000, and the other statesfurther large sums in addition to the municipalities.Money lent by the state is usually limited to buildinghouses for state employees and Insurance Boardslend on condition that the houses are let to personswho come under the insurance laws. The developmentof building societies has been promoted by theformation of general building associations of whichthe earliest was established in Düsseldorf in 1897 for the Rhineprovinces; under its influence one-fifth of the new housing providedin 1901 was erected by the societies. The example was followedat Frankfort, Münster and Wiesbaden. Housing by employers hasalso been carried out on a large scale in Germany. States andmunicipalities have to some extent built houses as employers, theformer chiefly for railwaymen, besides lending money to societiesfor the purpose; but most housing of this kind has been done byprivate employers. Krupps, who had built 4274 dwellings housingnearly 27,000 persons down to 1901, are the most famous example;but they are only one among many. In Rhineland and Westphaliaemployers had in 1902 provided 22,269 houses containing 62,539dwellings at a cost of £10,500,000; more than half the families sohoused belonged to the mining industry, the rest to various manufactures.These two provinces, in which industrial developmenthas been extremely rapid, are exceptional; but housing by employersis not confined to them. At Mannheim for instance over1000 working-class households have been so provided. At Nurembergthe Siemens Schuckert Company have encouraged an interestingsystem of collective building among their employees, by which 722dwellings have been provided.

Holland.—In 1901 a Public Health and a Housing Act werepassed, and these two embody most of the features of housing reformadopted in other countries. The first provides for a general sanitaryservice under the Ministry of the Interior. The second ordains thatlocal authorities shall frame by-laws for building and for the maintenanceand proper use of dwellings; that they shall inspect existingdwellings, order improvements or repairs or demolition; empowersthem to take land compulsorily for the purposes of the act, toprohibit building or rebuilding on sites reserved for public purposesand to make grants or loans to societies or companies operatingexclusively for the improvement of working-class dwellings. Ifthey fail to make by-laws the provincial authorities may takeaction. Land buying with a view to extensions has been adoptedby a number of municipalities including Amsterdam, Rotterdam,Utrecht and other important towns, and the practice is increasing.Amsterdam has also begun the systematic planning of extensions.There has been a little municipal building in some small places, butit is on an insignificant scale; the tendency is rather to favour societiesof public utility as in France, Germany and Belgium. The new lawsare too recent to have had much effect and housing reform is as yetin an early stage. Rents are high in the large towns, namely, 1room 1s. 8d. to 3s.; 2 rooms 2s. 6d. to 5s.; 3 rooms 3s. 6d. to 6s;4 rooms 4s. 2d. to 7s.

Italy.—A Housing of the Working Classes Act was passed in1903, to promote the improvement and provision of workmen’sdwellings. Municipalities have the power to purchase land compulsorilyfor housing purposes and also to build workmen’s dwellings.A few towns, of which Milan is one, have done so. There are buildingregulations relating to the area and height of rooms and the thicknessof walls. The antiquity of the Italian towns and the great quantityof old and insanitary building make housing improvement a verydifficult matter. La Società Umanitaria, a benevolent trust foundedby Prosper Loria of Milan in 1902, has taken up this subject amongothers and has built two model tenements, housing 2000 persons.

United States.—Interest in the housing question in the UnitedStates is confined to a few of the largest cities and can only be saidto be acute in New York, though there have been investigations bycommissions elsewhere and Miss Octavia Hill’s work in Londonhas found admirers and imitators in Philadelphia and Boston as wellas in New York. The evils of housing in New York have been thesubject of much sensational writing which has elevated them to theposition of a world-wide scandal. It is not necessary to accept allthe allegations made in order to see that several circumstances havecombined to produce an exceptional state of things in this great city.The limited space—the island or peninsula of Manhattan—in whichcentral New York is built has compelled the erection of large tenementblocks, otherwise rare in American towns; the incessant inrushof immigrants from the poorest parts of Europe has filled thesetenements with immense numbers of persons of many nationalitiesaccustomed to a low standard of living; the generally backwardstate of public sanitation in America, and the absence or evasion ofregulations and supervision, have permitted the erection of baddwellings, their deterioration into worse, and their misuse by excessiveovercrowding. Other large cities in which bad housing conditionsare known to exist are Chicago, Philadelphia, Boston, Baltimore,Cincinnati, Pittsburg, Jersey City. There are doubtless manyothers, but bad housing conditions are not so general in the UnitedStates as in Europe. Outside the very large cities there is morespace, more light and air, less crowding together, less darkness, dirtand dilapidation. Large houses, occupied by two or perhaps three families, are common, but they have more room space than is usualin Europe. The 18th annual report (1903) of the Commissionerof Labour gives the result of a special inquiry embracing 23,447families distributed in 33 states. The average number of roomswas 4.95 per family and 1.04 per individual. It is a fair inferencethat overcrowding is confined to a comparatively small number ofexceptional places. A large number of the schedules were furnished by the eminently urbanized and manufacturing states of NewYork, Pennsylvania, Massachusetts, Ohio and Illinois; and in allthese the average number of rooms to a family exceeded 4, rangingfrom 4.2 in Ohio to 5.5 in Massachusetts. The condition of homesas to sanitation and cleanliness was statistically stated thus:Sanitary condition—good 61.46%, fair 32,59%, bad 5.95%;Cleanliness—good 79.63%, fair 14.66 bad 5.71%. Otherspecial inquiries have been carried out in particular towns. In1891–1892 the tenements in Boston were investigated for theMassachusetts Labour Bureau, which found 3657 sleeping roomswithout outside windows and about 8% of the population living inconditions objectionable from one cause or another. In 1892Congress authorized a special inquiry into the slum population ofNew York, Chicago, Philadelphia and Baltimore, the results of whichwere published in the seventh special report (1894) of the UnitedStates Commissioner of Labour. It was estimated that the total“slum population” (presumably those living in unhealthy conditions)was—New York 360,000, Chicago 162,000, Philadelphia35,000, Baltimore 25,000. In Baltimore 530 families, consisting of1648 persons, were living in single rooms with an average of 3.15persons to a room; in Philadelphia 401 families were so living withan average of 3.11 persons to a room. The proportion of 1-roomdwellings was less in New York and Chicago. In New York 44.55%or nearly half the families investigated were found living in2–roomed dwellings, in Baltimore 27.88%, in Philadelphia 19.41%and in Chicago 19.14%. These figures conclusively prove thatEuropean conditions reproduce themselves in American cities.Poverty was not the cause, as the average earnings per familyranged from £3, 4s. a week in Baltimore to £4, 6s. a week in Chicago.Another official investigation in New York was carried out in 1895by the Tenement House Commission appointed by the State of NewYork. It reported “many houses in the city in an insanitary conditionwhich absolutely unfits them for habitation.” Further detailshave been compiled from the census by the New York Federationof Churches, chiefly relating to density of population in the city. In1900, out of a total of nearly 250,000 dwellings, 95,433 (38.2%)contained from 2 to 6 persons, 60,672 (24.2%) from 7 to 10 personsand 89,654 (35.9%) 11 persons or more. The density of populationfor the whole city as now constituted was 19 persons to the acre,in Manhattan 149; in the south-eastern district of Manhattan382 and in one ward 735. Between 1900 and 1905 the densityincreased in every district, and in the latter year there were 12 blockswith from 1000 to 1400 persons to the acre. The number of personsto the acre in London (1901) is 60.6; in the most densely populatedborough 182, and in the most densely populated district (a verysmall one) 396. This will give a measure of comparison. The largetenement blocks in New York have been constructed with far lessregard to health than those in Berlin, and reproduce in an aggravatedform the same evil of insufficient light and air. In place of theinadequate courts round which many are built in Berlin, the NewYork tenements have merely narrow air shafts. In 1904 there werereported to be 362,000 dark interior rooms, that is with no outsidewindows.

If American cities have nothing to learn from other countries inregard to bad housing, they have nothing to teach in the way ofreform. They are following Europe slowly and a long distancebehind. There is no serious attempt to deal with insanitary areasas they have been dealt with in England, or to prevent the creationof new ones by regulation and planning of extensions as in Germany,or to promote the provision of superior houses by organized publiceffort as in several countries. A little has been done in New Yorkto improve the worst housing. A Tenement House Act was passedafter the report of the Commission of 1895 and a Department formedto give effect to it. Some cleansing and repairing and insertion ofwindows is carried out every year, but more attention seems to bepaid to fire escapes. Societies for providing improved dwellingsexist in New York, Boston, Chicago and Philadelphia. The oldestis one formed in Boston in 1871, called the Co-operative BuildingCompany; it was followed in 1876 by an Improved DwellingsCompany in Brooklyn, and in 1879 by a similar society in Manhattan,and in 1885 by another in Boston. The largest concern of the kindis the City and Suburban Houses Company in New York, formed in1896 under the guidance of Dr E. R. L. Gould; it has built fourgroups of tenements housing 1238 families in the city and 112 houseson a suburban estate at Brooklyn; in all it has housed some 6000persons. More recently Mr Henry Phipps has given £200,000 forthe provision of model dwellings in New York, and a building hasbeen erected on the plan of the Maison des Enfants in Paris. InChicago the City Houses Association works at housing reforms invarious ways. There are some other institutions of a like kind,but the aggregate results are inconsiderable. Two other buildingagencies have done far more in the United States than philanthropicsocieties; these are the building and loan associations and privateemployers. The former are co-operative provident societies; theyare widely diffused throughout the United States and their operationsare on a very large scale. They date from 1831, when the OxfordProvident Building Association was formed at Frankfort, nearPhiladelphia. Pennsylvania has still the largest number of associations,but from 1843 onwards the movement spread rapidly andcontinuously in other states. The high-water mark appears to havebeen reached in 1897, when the total assets of the associationsamounted to about £133,000,000. In 1905 there were 5326 associationswith an aggregate membership of 1,686,611 and assets ofabout £130,000,000. The states of Pennsylvania and Ohio headthe list, but the movement is very strong in many others. It accountsfor the comparatively large number of houses owned by working-classfamilies in the United States. With regard to housing byemployers, no comprehensive information is available, but the totalamount is certainly considerable though probably not so large asin Germany or in France. Some of the better-known instances arethe Pelzer Manufacturing Company at Pelzer in South Carolina,which has built about 1000 dwellings; the Maryland Steel Companyat Sparrows Point, Maryland, 800 dwellings; Ludlow ManufacturingAssociates at Ludlow, Mass., 500 dwellings; Whitin MachineWorks at Whitinsville, Mass., 600 dwellings; Westinghouse AirBrake Co. at Wilmerding, Penn., 360 dwellings; Draper Co., Hopedale,Mass., 250 dwellings. These are all more or less “model”settlements, not in cities, but in outlying or country places, whereworks have been established, and that is generally true of housingby employers in the United States, whereas in Germany much hasbeen provided by them in the large towns. Rents are very muchhigher in American cities than in European towns of comparablesize and character.

Authorities.—Board of Trade Reports—“Cost of Living of theWorking Classes (England)” (1908); “Cost of Living in GermanTowns” (1908); “Cost of Living in French Towns” (1909). Proceedingsof International Housing Congress (London, 1907); TheNew Encyclopaedia of Social Reform; E. R. Dewsnup, The HousingProblem in England; T. C. Horsfall, The Example of Germany;J. S. Nettlefold, Practical Housing Reform; A. Shadwell, IndustrialEfficiency, ch. xi. on “Housing”; W. Thompson, The HousingHandbook, Housing up to Date.  (A. Sl.) 


From Belcher and Macartney, Later Renaissance Architecture in England, 1901. By permission of B. T. Batsford.
Fig. 14.—HAM HOUSE, PETERSHAM, 1610.
From Gotch, Architecture of the Renaissance in England, 1894. By permission of B. T. Batsford.
Fig. 15.—BRAMSHILL, HAMPSHIRE, 1612.


From Belcher and Macartney, Later Renaissance Architecture in England, By permission of B. T. Batsford.
Fig. 16.—THE EARL OF BURLINGTON’S VILLA, CHISWICK. EIGHTEENTH CENTURY.
From the same source as above.
Fig. 17.—HOUSES IN CAVENDISH SQUARE, LONDON. EIGHTEENTH CENTURY.